You bring up a lot of good points. I think this attitude is especially widespread among goldbugs too, for example. Makes it hard to take any of them seriously when they've been preaching to hide gold bars under your bed for decades.
I think overall the Austrians would do better by just focusing on smaller aspects of day-to-day effects of bad policy rather than an umbrella doom-and-gloom prediction.
It would help alleviate some of the issues you mentioned and also hopefully make their commentary relevant for the average person.
Curious to hear what you think.
Gold bugs are another great example.
I think overall the Austrians would do better by just focusing on smaller aspects of day-to-day effects of bad policy rather than an umbrella doom-and-gloom prediction.
This makes a lot of sense, but I think they're in a pickle. From my reading of Mises, I would say that a caricaturish-but-directionally-correct summary would be something like:
"Praxeology / catallactics is the One True Theoretical Foundation that, at scale, manifests in economics in the large. But action is individual, we can't generalize across people, time, or geography; and I don't even care what the data says about any of it, because we are reasoning forward from first principles."
But then if that's true, what's left for the economists? It's like they had their Euclid, and what work remains amounts to increasingly esoteric geometric proofs. I'm sure I've made my summary too extreme, but I don't think it's too too extreme. Mises rejects empiricism repeatedly in favor of the ideological purity that the deductive model provides. I've wondered about this for a while, perhaps @Undisciplined has some insight.
Anyway, I think drilling into elements of policy that are sideways w/ Austrian principles is good and helpful. Many of the arguments are both simple and compelling, and have the benefit of being explicable and comprehensible to normal people. You can read it as philosophy and get a lot out of it, or at least, I did. But then people want to know what's going to happen, and Austrians can't give them that in a satisfying way except to propose doom arising in months, years, or decades.
reply
I'd say you pretty well stated it.
There are still open questions in the Austrian tradition and scholars making headway on them, but a lot of the low-hanging fruit has been picked. Also, as you said, the very nature of Austrian Economics excludes precise predictions. That's actually where empirical work enters the picture
We can look at history and draw quantitative conclusions (this is what I do, btw) to questions where theory only gives directional answers. We can then make predictions based on those conclusions, but the caveat is always "If the prior relationship holds..."
My view is that there's a hierarchy of methodological approaches:
  1. Preferably, you can answer the question with the Austrian deductive approach that makes very minimal assumptions about people's preferences.
  2. If not, see if it can be answered using modern methods from abstract algebra and set theory, which might require some more assumptions about preferences, but aren't very restrictive.
  3. Create an experiment that closely resembles the question and see what people do.
  4. Finally, if all else fails, look at real world data and use econometrics to create natural experiments and see what people do.
reply